Home

  About Us

  Press Statements

  Position Papers   

  Basic Documents

  Resolutions

  Affiliates

  Forum

  Guest book  

  Links

 

 

 

 

How to Screw the Workers in the Emerging Economy:
APL Critique on the Report and Recommendations of the Congressional Commission on Labor

In 1997, the 10th Congress reaffirmed labor’s primacy as a “social economic force.” It said that “without the workers, capital cannot be translated into wealth; it is, by itself, worthless.”  

With these premises, the Congress ratified Joint Resolution 31 which created the Congressional Commission on Labor with a very clear set of objectives: to re-examine Government’s goals and objectives regarding labor, labor-management relations, trade unions and other related matters in light of the ravages of the “emerging world economic order.” 

Reading the resolution, one cannot help but wonder whether the ruling class has finally discovered their long lost humanity and has decided to throw its protective arms over the oppressed workers.  

Unfortunately, that is not to be so. After spending almost four years and more than 50 million pesos, the Labor Commission finally released its report entitled, “Human Capital in the Emerging Economy.” As expected, the “noble intentions” of Joint Resolution 31 was easily drowned out by the unrelenting mantra of neo-liberalism in the Labor Commission’s report. What started out as an investigation on how to protect the working people ended up as a report which glorifies the supposed virtues of the “free market”, deregulation, privatization, liberalization, labor flexibility and other neo-liberal prescriptions while paying lip service to the labor movement’s demands for strengthening workers’ and trade union rights. It is a patently anti-worker document which, if acted upon, would consign the working people to greater exploitation and condemn the trade unions to oblivion. The report, therefore, failed to live up to the mandate, if not the spirit, of Joint Resolution 31 that created it.  

While we note the GMA Administration’s lack of enthusiasm when it “received” the Labor Commission’s report during their formal presentation, we are however concerned that such a gesture did not in any way stopped the report’s translation into actual bills. In fact, we have received reports that Labor Commission has subcontracted a number of people to draft bills based on its report.  

This paper is aimed at presenting the critique of the Alliance of Progressive labor (APL). It is divided into two parts: the first sets out the critique of the APL to the report and recommendations of the Labor Commission; the second outlines the APL’s own recommendations.  

I. Critique of the Report of the Labor Commission 

A critique of the report must be done on two levels: on the process used by the Labor Commission in crafting its report; and, on the merits or demerits of its analyses and policy recommendations. 

A. The Moro-Moro Consultations: Critique on the Process 

The Labor Commission claimed that in the process of crafting its report and recommendations, it “convened 29 standing committee hearings, regional consultations and technical meetings,” excluding a number of fora and seminars on labor that it has organized. While this may be true, the quality of such “consultations” is at best dubious.  

Throughout the entire period of the Commissions’ work, the APL was rarely properly invited to attend. Either the invitations come in too late (which is usually the case) or invitations sent in advance would eventually be cancelled. In his foreword to the report, Sen. Gregorio Honasan gave a flimsy excuse for this: “We carried out our mandate in the midst of a political upheaval and despite other circumstances that affected the momentum of our study.”  But a number of labor leaders have a better, and probably a more realistic, explanation. They feel that the entire fiasco was, to a large extend, due to the Labor Commission’s insincerity in consulting the trade unions. 

On the single occasion where an APL representative was actually invited, on 17 January 2001 (while most of us were in EDSA waging People Power 2), the Labor Commission merely presented its report to the workers’ representatives instead of conducting a real consultation. Whatever criticisms which were offered after the presentation was perfunctorily brushed aside by the Committee representatives.  This buttressed the general feeling among workers’ representatives that the Labor Commission was merely going through the motions of conducting its mandatory consultations. 

This suspicion was confirmed when two weeks after, the Labor Commission finally presented its final report to the President. Obviously, the Labor Commission’s conclusions had been fixed and were on its way to the printing press long before they pretended to confer with worker’s representatives. 

To top it all, we have received information that the writing of the report was actually subcontracted to someone who was not a party to all those consultations and public discussions. 

B. Neoliberalism 101: Critique on the Content  

The report is a veritable pamphlet on neo-liberal propaganda. Except for a number of portions in a few chapters, the entire document was devoted to the teaching of the “merits” of further opening the economy to the global market, privatization, deregulation, liberalization, labor flexibility, etc. It is full of subjective statements as well as of conceptual statements which are not proven empirically. It even contains a number of contradictory recommendations. It should have been entitled as “Neo-liberalization 101” or “Neo-liberalism for Beginners.” An apt subtitle would have been “How to Screw the Workers in the Emerging Economy.” 

The overall focus of the report, as the report’s title misleadingly suggests, is on improving the country’s human capital. To do so, the report’s analysis revolved around jobs generation and the need to be competitive in the “global labor market”. 

1. Flawed Prescriptions on Generating Jobs. The report’s prescription for jobs generation is through the discredited formula of continued liberalization, export orientation and attracting foreign investments. It also calls for the continuation of sending OFWs abroad. Without even attempting to assess the impact of unbridled liberalization and privatization on unemployment, the report had the temerity to blame the “inability of the industrial sector to absorb more of the country’s labor force” to “a system of incentives that favored capital intensity and production for the domestic market.” (Page 28 underscoring supplied).  

It should be noted that the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP), the International Labour Organization (ILO) and other institutions, not to mention reputable economists, has produced mounting evidences of the ill effects of wanton liberalization, deregulation and privatization on workers’ rights and welfare everywhere. In fact, in a number of countries, including the Philippines has experienced “jobless growth.” The APL agrees that the unemployment crisis can only be licked by economic growth. However, much too often policy-makers, such as those who drafted the Labor Commission’s report, fail to distinguish between development as a measure of things getting better (as indicated by poverty reduction, greater social inclusion, etc.) and development as a measure of things getting bigger (in terms of more rapid growth in exports and gross national product). The APL believes that the long-term solution to achieve sustainable development is for government to balance export orientation with determined efforts to develop the domestic market. With our export destinations now under recession, there is no other way forward but to develop the local market. This would necessarily require the integration of the various small, separate "economies" that we find existing within the country through infrastructure development. But more importantly, this would also require the political will to institute a real asset reform not only in the rural areas (agrarian reform) but also in urban areas (urban land reform, profit sharing, etc.). 

2. Fetish on Labor Flexibility. The report’s prescription for labor’s competitiveness in the so-called “global labor market” is to allow more labor flexibility for employers; to increase labor productivity; retain the regional wage setting mechanism and pegging wage increases with productivity; and, by reforming the education system. Without presenting any empirical evidence, the report claimed that “flexible labor markets are important if the labor surplus is to be quickly absorbed…. Adjusting working hours or the size if the work force in response to output demand fluctuations or technological changes, to the extent that they allow companies to survive in the more competitive environment, also have long-term beneficial effects on employment.” (Pages 43-44) At the very least, such an unfounded proposal is irresponsible. The Labor Commission’s proposal to change policies on working arrangements and working time, especially the expansion of the scope of permissible contracting to work of all kinds violates workers' right to security of tenure.  The flexibility proposed by the Labor Commission will only legalize the current scheme employed to prevent workers from achieving regular employment status by hiding them behind other types of employment such as casual, contractual, agency-hired or probationary.  

On this score, it is emphasized that the proposal to expand the scope of permissible contracting greatly impairs the workers' right to self-organization.  A regime that allows employers to deny their workers regular status necessarily prevents them from organizing themselves for purposes of collective bargaining and mutual protection.  The APL strongly suspects that the Labor Commission’s proposal to supplant security of tenure with “security of employment” is only an elaborate way of directing workers not to aspire to stay employed at a particular enterprise.  In effect, the Labor Commission is telling workers to be content with the fact that they ARE employed, regardless of the work conditions and the times that they change employers.  The APL believes that the inherent costs of such a proposition to the individual and to society are all too obvious.   The guarantee extended to workers that they will stay employed unless there is just or authorized cause for their dismissal should never be diminished. 

3. Misleading Analysis on the Problem of Low Productivity. The paper pointed out the country’s problem regarding labor productivity. However, it deliberately misleads the Congress of its causes, by insinuating that workers are to be blamed. To buttress its argument, the paper even compared the country’s “unit cost of labor” with its neighbors (Page 40). But labor input is just one, though the most important, component of any product. Studies have suggested that the labor component of goods and services is only around 10% of the unit cost, in some cases it is even less. If we compare the unit costs for other costs of production (electricity, water, taxes, and other costs of doing business) we might see which is the real culprit in the lowering of efficiency! In agriculture, the paper bewailed the fact that “output per worker or labor productivity has remained low and stagnant for several years now” (Page 10). But it never even attempted to give an explanation. It should be pointed out this is the inevitable result of the government’s historic failure to implement real agrarian reform. So long as workers in the agricultural sector, as in any sector, toil without enjoying the fruits of their labor, productivity would definitely remain low. Thus why blame labor?  

To make matters worse, the Labor Commission recommended linking “collective bargaining and wage increases to company performance and productivity” (Page 71). This would deprive workers of their right to earn a guaranteed living wage. While the need for incentives to increase productivity is understandable, such incentives should only augment, not supplant, the workers' basic pay. The State should not revoke its guarantee to workers they will receive a level of wage which takes into account the demands of expenses necessary for a decent life.  

4. Irrational Justification for Maintaining the Current Wage Setting Mechanism. Without properly analyzing the merits and demerits of the country’s 12-year experience in regional minimum wage setting, the report simply stated that  whatever its shortcomings, the decentralized approach to wage setting is a second-best solution to the problem of protecting and enhancing the working people’s welfare without sacrificing the economy’s potential for dynamic growth.” (Page 42) This is, at best, a subjective statement for there is no empirical basis for this argument. Worse, it might have been a deliberate effort to gloss over the ineptitude of the Regional Tripartite Wages and Productivity Boards. By what measure was the Labor Committee able to say that this is the “second best solution”? To what have the Labor Commission compared the current system? Or was there any comparison made at all? Even a cursory review of the Wage Rationalization Act would have revealed that the law has effectively rendered the very notion of a “minimum wage” ineffective when it loaded too many contradictory objectives and criteria for setting the minimum wage. Experience has shown that instead of rationalizing wage setting, the RTWPBs has produced a steady supply of cheap labor by creating a convoluted system of minimum wage fixing and, as the Congressional Labor Commission reports, at least 300 wage levels around the country. Despite the trade union’s clamor for the abolition of the Regional, the Labor Commission never even bothered to render its own assessment on the RTWPB’s failure to "rationalize" wage fixing in the country and to secure a "decent standard of living" for the workers and their families. 

5. Privatizing Education. The report’s prescriptions for reforming the education system seems to have been lifted from the proposals contained in the Philippine Medium Term Development Plan for HRD. It calls for “the reduction of public subsidies to state universities and colleges by phasing them down or by devolving them to local government units or the private sector.”  (Page 88) Such a proposal would only widen the gap between the haves and the have nots as the plan would deprive tertiary education to the poor majority. It also recommends  forging closer links between educational and training institutions on one hand and industry on the other is critical to the success of academic and training programs.” (Page 56) This raises two critical issues: first, how do we ensure that on-the-job-training will not be abused by employers by taking on trainees in lieu of hiring regular employees as what is now happening in the hotel industry. (These trainees even pay the hotel just to be “trained”!); second, how do we ensure that there would be no loss of academic freedom as what is now happening in the United States and Canada where academic institutions sometimes tailor fit, in some cases completely censor, their research findings to suit the needs of their corporate sponsors? 

6. Paying Lip Service to Trade Union Rights. The report’s recommendations on strengthening trade unionism in the country amounted to nothing more than an afterthought. Although it extensively quoted the provisions in Article XIII, Section 3 of the 1987 Constitution on “Social Justice and Human Rights,” (Page 68) its positive recommendations for strengthening trade unionism in the country (examples: the removal of the role of the Court of Appeals in labor adjudication process; the concept of multi-form bargaining such as industry bargaining; elimination of “unnecessary state interventions in union formation, membership and the conduct of its internal affairs”) was effectively undermined by the overarching framework of labor flexibility arrangements. In fact, the reports’ drafters even gave a glimpse on their ulterior motives when they wrote that, “Globalization will even create the need for more workers’ associations as factory-based unions and CBAs are replaced by flexible working conditions as the norm.” (Page 84 underscoring supplied)  

7. Other Anti-worker Recommendations. Aside from those previously mentioned, the report is replete with other patently anti-labor recommendations. Here are some of nastiest ones:  

a)      “Revise the Labor Code to make its provisions on labor standards reflect the new realities in the labor market.” (Page 90) This would essentially enshrine labor flexibility measures in the Labor Code.  

b)      “Leadership should be encouraged from within; officers of unions should be employees of the company concerned.” (Page 70)This could lead to an undesirable situation where federation officers are barred from collective bargaining and other trade union activities in the enterprise level. 

c)      "’Unfair labor practice’ provision should be decriminalized to provide an improved climate for the employment relationship.” (Page 72) This would definitely open the floodgates to workers’ exploitation by unscrupulous employers. On the contrary, what is actually needed is to simplify the filing of criminal cases against employers found to be violating labor standards. 

d)      “The idea of self-regulation (of overseas manning industries) is still important to consider, in the case of industries where the private sector has a clear lead over the government in expertise and capability to respond to changes. Examples of these industries are information technology and the maritime industry.” This would allow unscrupulous manning agencies to practice their exploitative ways with greater freedom.  

e)      “The transformation of the DOLE into a Department of Employment” where its primary function is jobs generation. This would rollback the DOLE’s  role in managing  industrial relations. 

f)        The merger of National Conciliation and Mediation Board (NCMB) and the NLRC “into a new body of settling disputes” to be called as the National Labor Relations Board. This would only mean the absorption of corrupt officials into the new agency.  

II. APL Recommendation: Scrap the Report of the Labor Committee  

Amending the Philippine Labor Code is long overdue. The unemployment crisis and the “race to the bottom” wages engendered by current strain of globalization has plunged vast numbers of the working people into poverty. There is pressing need to reform the country’s outdated labor code to provide workers with solid guarantees for protection. But the Labor Commission’s report is out of sync with this objective.  

Clearly, the report has failed to live up to the mandate, if not the spirit, of Joint Resolution 31 which created it. While the resolution reaffirms the primacy of labor over capital, the report, despite its pretensions, equates labor as nothing but another commodity. Rather than improve the country’s human capital, as suggested by its title, the report actually consigns the working people to greater exploitation and condemns the trade unions to oblivion. This is hardly surprising. After all, for neo-liberals, workers are mere inputs to production that have to be maximized, and trade unions and collective bargaining agreements are nothing more than rigidities in the market that must be quickly dispensed with. 

On this light, one can safely conclude that the Labor Commission’s report is nothing less than a betrayal of the interests of the working people and their trade unions. Not to mention that it was a waste of public funds! 

The APL calls on the GMA administration and the 12th Congress to: 

1.      Scrap the report of the Labor Commission and to investigate Commission’s Secretariat for deliberately misleading the Congress with its report;   

2.      Restructure the composition of the Labor Commission into a tripartite body with equal number of representatives from the social partners, and extend its life to study and recommend laws, policies and programs concerning workers' rights and welfare; 

3.      Prioritize the passage of the following House Bills:

a)      H.B. 224 (An act Strengthening the Constitutional Right to Security of Tenure)

b)      H.B. 3040 (An Act Strengthening the Workers' Constitutional Right to Self-Organization)

c)      H.B 2899 (An Act Amending Presidential Decree No. 442, As Amended, Otherwise Known as the labor Code of the Philippines, and Providing for the Rationalization of Wage Levels on a National or Industrial Basis)  

4.      Enact laws and that would:

a)      Guarantee full trade union rights, including the right to collectively bargain and to strike, to public sector workers;

b)      Simplify strike procedure and remove restrictions to the right to strike. This includes an anti-scab provision and the repeal of the free ingress-egress provision. Furthermore, violation of CBA provisions, including refusal to comply with the grievance machinery or to submit unresolved grievance to arbitration should be included within the ambit of unfair labor practices. 

5.      Guidelines to prevent abuse of the power to assume jurisdiction over labor disputes. 

6.      Reform the labor adjudication system by abolishing the NLRC to streamline and simplify procedure in labor disputes; 

7.      Ratify all ILO Conventions. 

8.      Institutionalize workers' representation by in all trade negotiations prior to making any commitments as well as in other government institutions whose policies/programs impacts on labor, both in the formal and informal sector.  And by setting-up a tripartite economic council where major economic policies could be formulated, coordinated and monitored.

 

Home             Back

Alliance of Progressive Labor (APL) 2002
Manila, Philippines

email: apl@surfshop.net.ph

http://aplnet.tripod.com